Home > The Economics Profession > “Like a Dog Walking on its Hind Legs”: Krugman’s Minsky Model

“Like a Dog Walking on its Hind Legs”: Krugman’s Minsky Model

from Steve Keen

I recently fired a stray shot at Paul Krugman over his joke paper “The Theory of Interstellar Trade” (Krugman 2010), for which I have duly apologized. However in that apology I noted that Krugman has also recently published a draft academic paper presenting a New Keynesian model of debt deflation, “Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo approach” (Eggertsson and Krugman 2010), and I observed that I wish this paper was in fact a joke. Here’s why (this is a modified extract from my forthcoming second edition of Debunking Economics, which will be published by Zed Books in about September or October this year).

Though I applaud Krugman for being probably the first neoclassical economist to attempt to model Minsky after decades of ignoring him, the model itself embodies everything that is bad in neoclassical economics.

This reflect poorly, not so much Krugman—who has done the best he can with the neoclassical toolset to model what he thinks Minsky said—but on the toolset itself, which is utterly inappropriate for understanding the economy in which we actually live.

There is a pattern to neoclassical attempts to increase the realism of their models that is as predictable as sunrise—but nowhere near as beautiful. The author takes the core model—which cannot generate the real world phenomenon under discussion—and then adds some twist to the basic assumptions which, hey presto, generate the phenomenon in some highly stylized way. The mathematics (or geometry) of the twist is explicated, policy conclusions (if any) are then drawn, and the paper ends.

The flaw with this game is the very starting point, and since Minsky put it best, I’ll use his words to explain it:

Can “It”—a Great Depression—happen again? And if “It” can happen, why didn’t “It” occur in the years since World War II? These are questions that naturally follow from both the historical record and the comparative success of the past thirty-five years. To answer these questions it is necessary to have an economic theory which makes great depressions one of the possible states in which our type of capitalist economy can find itself. (Minsky 1982, p. xii; emphasis added)

The flaw in the neoclassical game is that it never achieves Minsky’s final objective, because the “twist” that the author adds to the basic assumptions of the neoclassical model are never incorporated into its core. The basic theory therefore remains one in which the key phenomenon under investigation—in this case, the crucial one Minsky highlights of how Depressions come about—cannot happen. The core theory remains unaltered—rather like a dog that learns how to walk on its hind legs, but which then reverts to four legged locomotion when the performance is over.

Figure 1: http://www.life.com/image/53019060;

Krugman himself is unlikely to stop walking on two legs—he enjoys standing out in the crowd of neoclassical quadrupeds—but the pack will return to form once this crisis ultimately gives way to tranquility.

The scholarship of ignorance and the ignorance of scholarship

Krugman’s paper cites 19 works, three of which are non-neoclassical—Fisher’s classic 1933 “debt deflation” paper, Minsky’s last book Stabilizing an Unstable Economy (Minsky 1986), and Richard Koo’s The Holy Grail of Macroeconomics: Lessons from Japan’s Great Recession (Koo 2009). The other 16 include one empirical study (McKinsey Global Institute 2010) and 15 neoclassical papers written between 1989 (Bernanke and Gertler 1989) and 2010 (Woodford 2010)—5 of which are papers by Krugman or his co-author.

Was this the best he could have done? Hardly! For starters, the one Minsky reference he used was, in my opinion, Minsky’s worst book—and I’m speaking as someone in a position to know. Anyone wanting to get a handle on the Financial Instability Hypothesis from Minsky himself would be far better advised to read the essays in Can “It” Happen Again? (Minsky 1982), or his original book John Maynard Keynes (Minsky 1975)—which despite its title is not a biography, but the first full statement of the hypothesis.

Krugman’s ignorance of Minsky prior to the crisis was par for the course amongst neoclassical authors, since they only read papers published in what they call the leading journals—such as the American Economic Review—which routinely reject non-neoclassical papers without even refereeing them.

Almost all academic papers on or by Minsky have been published in non-mainstream journals—the American Economic Review (AER), for example, has published a grand total of two papers on or by Minsky, one in 1957 (Minsky 1957) and the other in 1971 (Minsky 1971). If the AER and the other so-called leading journals were all you consulted as you walked up and down the library aisles, you wouldn’t even know that Minsky existed—and most neoclassicals didn’t know of him until after 2007.

Before the “Great Recession” too, you might have been justified in ignoring the other journals—such as the Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, the Journal of Economic Issues, the Review of Political Economy (let alone the Nebraska Journal of Economics and Business where several of Hyman’s key papers were published) because these were “obviously” inferior journals, where papers not good enough to make it into the AER, the Economic Journal, Econometrica and so on were finally published.

But after the Great Recession, when the authors who foresaw the crisis came almost exclusively from the non-neoclassical world (Bezemer 2009; Bezemer 2010), and who were published almost exclusively in the non-mainstream journals, neoclassical economists like Krugman should have eaten humble pie and consulted the journals they once ignored.

That might have been difficult once: which journals would you look in, if all you knew was that the good stuff—the models that actually predicted what happened—hadn’t been published in the journals you normally consulted? But today, with the Internet, that’s not a problem. Academic economists have as their bibliographic version of Google the online service Econlit, and there it’s impossible to do even a cursory search on Minsky and not find literally hundreds of papers on or by him. For example, a search last month on the keywords “Minsky” and “model” turned up 106 references (including three by yours truly–Keen 1995; Keen 1996; Keen 2001, and one more will probably be there now ; Keen 2011).

Figure 2: The result of a search on “Minsky” and “model” in Econlit

27 of these are available in linked full text (one of which is also by yours truly–Keen 1995; see Figure 3), so that you can download them direct to your computer from within Econlit, while others can be located by searching through other online sources, without having to trundle off to a physical library to get them. To not have any references at all from this rich literature is simply poor scholarship. Were Krugman a student of mine, he’d get a fail for this part of his essay.

Figure 3: My paper which is downloadable directly from Econlit

So in attempting to model a debt crisis in a capitalist economy, Krugman has used as his guide Fisher’s pivotal paper, Minsky’s worst book, and about 10 neoclassical references written by someone other than himself and his co-author. How did he fare?

Minsky without money (let alone endogenous money)

One thing I can compliment Krugman for is honestly about the state of neoclassical macroeconomic modeling before the Great Recession. His paper opens with the observation that:

“If there is a single word that appears most frequently in discussions of the economic problems now afflicting both the United States and Europe, that word is surely “debt”” (Eggertsson and Krugman 2010, p. 1)

He then admits that private debt played no role in neoclassical macroeconomic models before the crisis:

Given both the prominence of debt in popular discussion of our current economic difficulties and the long tradition of invoking debt as a key factor in major economic contractions, one might have expected debt to be at the heart of most mainstream macroeconomic models—especially the analysis of monetary and fiscal policy. Perhaps somewhat surprisingly, however, it is quite common to abstract altogether from this feature of the economy. Even economists trying to analyze the problems of monetary and fiscal policy at the zero lower bound—and yes, that includes the authors—have often adopted representative-agent models in which everyone is alike, and in which the shock that pushes the economy into a situation in which even a zero interest rate isn’t low enough takes the form of a shift in everyone’s preferences. (p. 2; emphasis added)

However, from this mea culpa, it’s all downhill, because Krugman makes no fundamental shift from a neoclassical approach; all he does is modify his base “New Keynesian” model to incorporate debt as he perceives it. On this front, he falls into the neoclassical trap of being incapable of conceiving that aggregate debt can have a macroeconomic impact:

Ignoring the foreign component, or looking at the world as a whole, the overall level of debt makes no difference to aggregate net worth — one person’s liability is another person’s asset. (p. 3)

This one sentence establishes that Krugman has failed to comprehend Minsky, who realized—as did Schumpeter and Marx before him—that growing debt in boosts aggregate demand. Minsky put it this way:

If income is to grow, the financial markets… must generate an aggregate demand that, aside from brief intervals, is ever rising. For real aggregate demand to be increasing… it is necessary that current spending plans, summed over all sectors, be greater than current received income … It follows that over a period during which economic growth takes place, at least some sectors finance a part of their spending by emitting debt or selling assets. (Minsky 1982, p. 6)

Schumpeter made the same case in a more systematic way, by focusing upon the role of entrepreneurs in capitalism. He made the point that an entrepreneur is someone with an idea but not necessarily the finance needed to put that idea into motion. The entrepreneur therefore must borrow money to be able to purchase the goods and labor needed to turn her idea into a final product. This money, borrowed from a bank, adds to the demand for existing goods and services generated by the sale of those existing goods and services:

THE fundamental notion that the essence of economic development consists in a different employment of existing services of labor and land leads us to the statement that the carrying out of new combinations takes place through the withdrawal of services of labor and land from their previous employments… this again leads us to two heresies: first to the heresy that money, and then to the second heresy that also other means of payment, perform an essential function, hence that processes in terms of means of payment are not merely reflexes of processes in terms of goods. In every possible strain, with rare unanimity, even with impatience and moral and intellectual indignation, a very long line of theorists have assured us of the opposite…

From this it follows, therefore, that in real life total credit must be greater than it could be if there were only fully covered credit. The credit structure projects not only beyond the existing gold basis, but also beyond the existing commodity basis. (Schumpeter 1934, pp. 95, 101; emphasis added)

This argument is a pivotal part of my analysis, in which I define aggregate demand as the sum of income plus the change in debt—as regular readers of this blog would know.

Krugman also has no understanding of the endogeneity of credit money—that banks create an increase in spending power by simultaneously creating money and debt. Lacking any appreciation of how money is created in a credit-based economy, Krugman sees lending as simply a transfer of spending power from one agent to another, and neither banks nor money exist in the model he builds.

Instead, in place of the usual neoclassical trick of modeling the entire economy as a single representative agent, he models it as two agents, one of whom is impatient while the other is patient. Debt is simply a transfer of spending power from the patient agent to the impatient one, and therefore the debt itself has no macroeconomic impact—it simply transfers spending power from the patient agent to the impatient one. The only way this can have a macroeconomic impact is if the “impatient” agent is somehow constrained in ways that the patient agent is not, and that’s exactly how Krugman concocts a macroeconomic story out of this neoclassical microeconomic fantasy:

In what follows, we begin by setting out a flexible-price endowment model in which “impatient” agents borrow from “patient” agents [where what is borrowed is not money, but “”risk-free bonds denominated in the consumption good” (p. 5)], but are subject to a debt limit. If this debt limit is, for some reason, suddenly reduced, the impatient agents are forced to cut spending; if the required deleveraging is large enough, the result can easily be to push the economy up against the zero lower bound. If debt takes the form of nominal obligations, Fisherian debt deflation magnifies the effect of the initial shock. (Eggertsson and Krugman 2010, p. 3)

He then generalizes this with “a sticky-price model in which the deleveraging shock affects output instead of, or as well as, prices” (p. 3), brings in nominal prices without money by imagining “that there is a nominal government debt traded in zero supply… We need not explicitly introduce the money supply” (p. 9), models production under imperfect competition (p. 11)—yes, the preceding analysis was of a no-production economy in which agents simply trade existing “endowments” of goods distributed like Manna from heaven—dds a Central Bank that sets the interest rate (in an economy without money) by following a Taylor Rule, and on it goes.

The mathematics is complicated, and real brain power was exerted to develop the argument—just as, obviously, it takes real brain power for a poodle to learn how to walk on its hind legs. But it is the wrong mathematics because the analysis compares two equilibria separated by time rather than being truly dynamic by analyzing change over time regardless of whether equilibrium applies or not, and wasted brain power because the initial premise—that aggregate debt has no macroeconomic effects—was false.

Krugman at least acknowledges the former problem—that the dynamics are crude:

The major limitation of this analysis, as we see it, is its reliance on strategically crude dynamics. To simplify the analysis, we think of all the action as taking place within a single, aggregated short run, with debt paid down to sustainable levels and prices returned to full ex ante flexibility by the time the next period begins. (p. 23)

But even here, I doubt that he would consider genuine dynamic modeling without the clumsy neoclassical device of assuming that all economic processes involve movements from one equilibrium to another. Certainly this paper remains true to the perspective he gave in 1996 when speaking to the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy:

I like to think that I am more open-minded about alternative approaches to economics than most, but I am basically a maximization-and-equilibrium kind of guy. Indeed, I am quite fanatical about defending the relevance of standard economic models in many situations…

He described himself as an “evolution groupie” to this audience, but then made the telling observation that:

Most economists who try to apply evolutionary concepts start from some deep dissatisfaction with economics as it is. I won’t say that I am entirely happy with the state of economics. But let us be honest: I have done very well within the world of conventional economics. I have pushed the envelope, but not broken it, and have received very widespread acceptance for my ideas. What this means is that I may have more sympathy for standard economics than most of you. My criticisms are those of someone who loves the field and has seen that affection repaid.

Krugman’s observations on methodology in this speech also highlight why he was incapable of truly comprehending Minsky—because he still starts from the premise that neoclassical economics itself has proven to be false, that macroeconomics must be based on individual behavior:

Economics is about what individuals do: not classes, not “correlations of forces”, but individual actors. This is not to deny the relevance of higher levels of analysis, but they must be grounded in individual behavior. Methodological individualism is of the essence. (Krugman 1996; emphases added)

No it’s not: methodological individualism is part of the problem, as the Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu conditions establish—a point that neoclassical economists have failed to comprehend, but whose import was realized by Alan Kirman:

If we are to progress further we may well be forced to theorise in terms of groups who have collectively coherent behaviour. Thus demand and expenditure functions if they are to be set against reality must be defined at some reasonably high level of aggregation. The idea that we should start at the level of the isolated individual is one which we may well have to abandon. (Kirman 1989, p. 138)

So while Krugman reaches some policy conclusions with which I concur—such as arguing against government austerity programs during a debt-deflationary crisis—his analysis is proof for the prosecution that even “cutting edge” neoclassical economics, by continuing to ignore the role of aggregate debt, is part of the problem of the Great Recession, not part of its solution.

References

Bernanke, B. S. and M. Gertler (1989). “Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations.” American Economic Review
79: 14-31.

Bezemer, D. J. (2009). “No One Saw This Coming”: Understanding Financial Crisis Through Accounting Models. Groningen, The Netherlands, Faculty of Economics University of Groningen.

Bezemer, D. J. (2010). “Understanding financial crisis through accounting models.” Accounting, Organizations and Society
35(7): 676-688.

Eggertsson, G. B. and P. Krugman (2010). Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo approach.

Keen, S. (1995). “Finance and Economic Breakdown: Modeling Minsky’s ‘Financial Instability Hypothesis.’.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics
17(4): 607-635.

Keen, S. (1996). “The Chaos of Finance: The Chaotic and Marxian Foundations of Minsky’s ‘Financial Instability Hypothesis.’.” Economies et Societes
30(2-3): 55-82.

Keen, S. (2001). Minsky’s Thesis: Keynesian or Marxian? The economic legacy of Hyman Minsky. Volume 1. Financial Keynesianism and market instability. R. Bellofiore and P. Ferri. Cheltenham, U.K., Edward Elgar: 106-120.

Keen, S. (2011). “A monetary Minsky model of the Great Moderation and the Great Recession.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
In Press, Corrected Proof.

Kirman, A. (1989). “The Intrinsic Limits of Modern Economic Theory: The Emperor Has No Clothes.” Economic Journal
99(395): 126-139.

Koo, R. (2009). The Holy Grail of Macroeconomics: Lessons from Japan’s Great Recession. Wiley.

Krugman, P. (1996). “What Economists Can Learn From Evolutionary Theorists.” from http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/evolute.html.

Krugman, P. (2010). “THE THEORY OF INTERSTELLAR TRADE.” Economic Inquiry
48(4): 1119-1123.

McKinsey Global Institute (2010). Debt and Deleveraging: The Global Credit Bubble and its Economic Consequences.

Minsky, H. (1957). “Monetary Systems and Accelerator Models.” American Economic Review
67: 859-883.

Minsky, H. P. (1971). “The Allocation of Social Risk: Discussion.” American Economic Review
61(2): 389-390.

Minsky, H. P. (1975). John Maynard Keynes. New York, Columbia University Press.

Minsky, H. P. (1982). Can “it” happen again? : essays on instability and finance. Armonk, N.Y., M.E. Sharpe.

Minsky, H. P. (1986). Stabilizing an unstable economy, Twentieth Century Fund Report series, New Haven and London: Yale University Press.

Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development : an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest and the business cycle. Cambridge, Massachusetts, Harvard University Press.

Woodford, M. (2010). Simple Analytics Of The Government Expenditure Multiplier. Nber Working Paper Series. Cambridge, MA, National Bureau Of Economic Research.

  1. paul davidson
    March 10, 2011 at 1:16 pm

    Krugman is like some of ricardian scholars in Keynes’s day , according to Keynes, whose “common sense canot helpbreaking in–with injury to their logical conxixtency” ==GT p/ 192

    Paul

  2. March 10, 2011 at 2:25 pm

    One more mainstream paper on Minsky:

    Lance Taylor and Stephen A. O’Connell, A Minsky Crisis, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 100, Supplement (1985), pp. 871-885.

  3. March 10, 2011 at 2:34 pm

    I like Krugman because I think that, despite his clinging to the neoclassical paradigm, he’s actually a very smart person. You can learn a lot from the mistakes of smart people.

    • Dr Anonymous
      March 11, 2011 at 1:50 am

      Yes, you can learn that it’s possible to write several thousand words on the financial crisis in an article entitled “How Did Economists Get It So Wrong” without once mentioning the word “Marx.” Even though a short, stylized, offbase history of ‘economics’ as a field is presented therein.

      • Alice
        March 11, 2011 at 8:19 am

        No one wants to mention Marx because perhaps he will prove the most accurate economist predictor of all, despite the gloominess of his predictions, in the long run…. many economists appear to think a happy outcome is possible despite overwhelming evidence to the contrary which current economics and policy is doing very little to mitigate.
        Nothing like going down the entirely wrong road for three decades or more….my god…the change needed is bigger than any economics that exists, that currently pretends to aid policy direction.

  4. merijnknibbe
    March 10, 2011 at 3:49 pm

    Time and again debt comes popping up, to the embarrassment of many an economist. And debt is central to the work of, among others, Keen. The main metric to describe macro ecconomies are the National Accounts. We have to ask the question how (modern) National Accounts treat debt, as Keen does not always seems at ease with these national accounts. The good news: these national accounts treat debt the same way as Keen does.

    First, some theory: contrary to a neo classical dogma, money does not solve the problem of the ‘mutual coincidence of wants’, it causes the problem of the ‘mutual coincidence of wants’, a problem which is either solved by saving or by borrowing. Take, as an instance, a dowry or a mortgage. Without money there would be no (monetary) dowries for which money has to be saved (an enormous problem in large parts of the world!), without money no houses for sale and no need for mortgages. It’s money that necessitates monetary borrowing, not the other way around.

    Is this reflected in the national accounts? Yes, it is. When we look at the sector accounts of the National Accounts, in this case, for simplicity, the sector households, we see that the ‘means’ of households which are used for consumption and investments are defined as (simplified):

    (Production – intermediate use) + (net taxes, net subsidies, net social transfers) + (net saving in a year) + (net borrowing in a year) + (net property income). That’s the money available, production minus intermediate use being equal to value added produced directly be households (take, for instance, a traditional farm). ‘Means’ are, as in teh case of Keen’s work, inclusive of net borrowing and saving!

    These ‘means’ are used for consumption, cash hoardings, financial assets, or (net) investments as well as to pay wages and some capital transfers and the purchase of ‘non produced non financial assets’.

    The point: neo-classical macro economics is not consistent with the national accounts, which do describe the actual flows of money. Keen’s work is. Even the ‘non produced assets’ have their place, as national accounts describe the real world. They do so in a stylized, simplified way. But this stylized way is a simplification of reality – unlike the stylized formula’s of neo classical economics, which are no simplification of reality, but a description of an invented world, a map of Utopia. An Utopia without debts and non-produced assets. An Utopia inconsistent with even a stylized description of reality.

  5. D R
    March 10, 2011 at 5:29 pm

    Shall we break this down?

    The quote from Minsky reads “some sectors finance a part of their spending by emitting debt or selling assets.” Note first of all that this means one or more of…

    a) going into debt directly to the seller, in which case the assets of the seller are increased by exactly the same amount as the the debt of the purchaser. (We might also consider the loss of inventory as an asset loss to to the seller which exactly cancels the asset gain and vice-versa, etc, but let us hereafter consider inventory strictly as a matter of current production)

    b) purchasing currently-produced goods or services by trading away financial (possibly cash) assets to the seller, in which case the assets of the seller are increased by exactly the same amount as the loss in assets of the purchaser

    c) going into debt to a third party in return for cash, in which case the soon-to-be purchaser’s assets have gone up by exactly the same amount the third-party’s assets have fallen (the cash transfer) and the soon-to-be purchaser’s debt has gone up by exactly the same amount that the third-party’s assets have gone up (the non-cash side of the transaction) In sum, the gross assets of each is unchanged and the gross debt of each is also unchanged although the composition of assets and debt for each party are changed.

    That is, if inventories are taken into account, there can be no changes in assets or debt for any party as a result of the trade. Furthermore, if inventories are considered as part of current production rather than capital, then the total joint assets and debt for the parties are unchanged.

    Consequently, if “some sectors” are increasing net debt, there must be some other sector (possibly external) which is increasing net assets.

    Insofar as we are summing spending “over all sectors” and finding an increase in debt the “other sector” is implicitly external.

    So Minsky is saying that current spending may exceed current income to the extent there is an increase in (net) external debt. This is pretty obvious from a national-accounts standpoint.

    Current spending is C+I+G, while current income is C+I+G+X-M. Thus, current spending less current income is equal to the trade deficit (and more broadly, the current account deficit when net transfers from the external sector are included in income)

    So when Krugman considers the world as a whole (equivalently, any closed economy) there can be no aggregate current account imbalance and current spending must equal current debt. On the other hand, Minsky implicitly has assumed an external sector, thereby allowing for the possibility of an imbalance.

    There is no contradiction between Krugman and Minsky here– merely a failure to distinguish between closed and open economies.

  6. D R
    March 10, 2011 at 6:55 pm

    I of course meant “current spending must equal current income” not “current debt” which would make no sense whatsoever.

  7. merijnknibbe
    March 10, 2011 at 7:58 pm

    @DR,

    a problem with debt and the National Accounting identity (which always holds) is that this identity does not include existing and non-produced assets. C and I do not include the purchase of an already built home, only of newly built homes. When debt is used to purchase existing houses or stock, prices of these assets might go up. In that case, debt financed current spending (including spending on second hand goods like houses and stock) may be higher than current income. It becomes slightly complicated when people who sell these high priced houses spend their gains on purchases of produced goods – that does increase (nominal) income. Whenever companies succeed in expanding production, this increase in nominal income might equal a rise in real production. Otherwise, it might just lead to inflation.

    • D R
      March 10, 2011 at 9:48 pm

      I think you’re still missing the point.

      If “current spending” includes “spending on second hand goods” then so does “current income” include selling of second hand goods. The difference is unchanged.

      Hence, GDP accounting for “currently produced” goods and services and the folding of inventory accumulations into investment.

      We can always go ahead and talk about “spending on current production plus spending on assets” and then “income from current production” but an excess of the former over the latter does in no accounting whatsoever imply an increase in debt, either gross or net. It’s a piece of arithmetic devoid of any meaning, just as if I said “dogs born minus apples fallen from trees”

      … Unless of course, you mean “plus net spending on assets” in which case we are back to the open/closed economy issue.

  8. O S
    March 11, 2011 at 6:33 am

    Lance Taylor’s paper, mainstream? How come?

  9. paolo leon
    March 11, 2011 at 9:03 am

    Minsky and Keen are right. In bull markets (these, I suppose can be recognized as existing) when values on stock exchanges and other trading means increase, leverage increases and such rise can be spent in goods and services: thus a boom is produced out of financial markets. If debt can increase, because financial market prices increase, then expenditure increases. For this niot to happen, all the increased spending should be allocated on the financial markets: and this recreates a bull market all the time. If households transform their increased home values in new goods and services, and their apparent well being increases, there will be a lesser pressure on firms to increase wages and salaries: a chasm is induced between wage income and leverage income. The bull markets induce a worsening income distribution.

  10. March 13, 2011 at 4:03 pm

    “…a chasm is induced between wage income and leverage income.”

    I too sure thought that was the problem, but I keep looking this post over to see what I am not getting. I thought the whole problem was: The nominal parity of debt to asset (everybody’s debt is somebody’s asset) is not the same as the real parity of debt to asset. If the assets are real productive goods and services, the constant generation of demand through debt results in market glut; prices fall, profits fall, recession, depression, collapse. If the assets are debts that are in turn debts (those CDO’s and CDO squared inventions), the profits and wages from real goods and services don’t keep up with the bubble, and so we get the pop, prices fall, profits fall, recession, depression, collapse….

    So, the normal capitalist economy is one that ping-pongs between those extremes. Equilibrium points are at best passed through as the economy naturally moves away from them….????

  11. March 14, 2011 at 4:27 pm

    @OS, Taylor’s paper wasn’t mainstream, the journal (QJE) was.

  1. No trackbacks yet.

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

%d bloggers like this: