Home > depression, The Economics Profession > Sweden hit by deflation — a sad and worrying reminder of the impotence of mainstream economics

Sweden hit by deflation — a sad and worrying reminder of the impotence of mainstream economics

form Lars Syll

Sweden is according to new statistics from  Statistics Sweden in a state of deflation. The inflation rate was -0.6 percent in March.

To a large extent the deflation is caused by tight monetary and fiscal policies  pursued by Sweden’s  Central Bank and the government. With a very defensive fiscal policy and a targeted inflation rate set at a very low level, real inflation has during the last 2-3 years been very close to zero, and now even negative. Another consequence of the austere fiscal and monetary policies is that overall unemployment is still at almost 9 % and youth unemployment close to 26 %.

This is deeply worrying.

So yours truly thought he should give the Swedish Fed and the Swedish finance minister – Anders Borg –  a suggestion for reading …

Zoltan Pozsnar and Paul McCulley have written an absolutely splendid essay on what a liquidity trap means and why mainstream neoclassical economics has nothing to offer in way of solving the problems that it brings along – and why it is so important to get hold of the insights that Fisher, Keynes, Minsky and Krugman have given us on debt-deflation processes and liquidity traps:

A liquidity trap is a circumstance in which the private sector is deleveraging in the wake of enduring negative animal spirits caused by the bursting of joint asset price and credit bubbles that leave privatesector balance sheets severely damaged. In a liquidity trap the animal spirits of the private sector cannot be revived by a reduction in short-term interest rates because there is no demand for credit. This effectively means that conventional monetary policy does not work in a liquidity trap …

Deleveraging can be rational for an individual household. It can be rational for an individual corporation. It can be rational for an individual country. However, in the aggregate it begets the paradox of thrift1: what is rational at the microeconomic level is irrational at the community, or macroeconomic, level.

This is not to say that the private sector should not deleverage. It has to. It is a part of the economy’s healing process and a necessary first step toward a self-sustaining economic recovery.

However, deleveraging is a beast of a burden that capitalism cannot bear alone. At the macro level, deleveraging must be a managed process: for the private sector to deleverage without causing a depression, the public sector has to move in the opposite direction and re-lever by effectively viewing the balance sheets of the monetary and fiscal authorities as a consolidated whole.

Fiscal austerity does not work in a liquidity trap and makes as much sense as putting an anorexic on a diet. Yet, “diets” are the very prescriptions that fiscal austerians have imposed (or plan to impose) in the U.S., U.K. and Eurozone. Austerians fail to realize, however, that everyone cannot save at the same time and that in liquidity traps, the paradox of thrift and depression are fellow travelers that are functionally intertwined.

Historically, austerity has only worked when accompanied by monetary easing – where wealth effects and stronger private demand for credit helped offset the effects of fiscal austerity – and/or a weaker currency – which helped steal others’ demand.

In a liquidity trap, however, austerity cannot work because monetary policy is neither functioning correctly nor able offset lost demand, and weak currencies work only at a time of strong global demand and only for individual countries, not for several major countries at one time. Imposing austerity without potential offsets and at a time of weak global aggregate demand is deflationary, which makes deleveraging much harder, balance sheet repair much slower and recovery much less likely to achieve. In a liquidity trap, governments have no logical option but to borrow and to invest.

How could governments borrow more if government debt is also a problem everywhere? Would it not be irresponsible to increase borrowing at a time of record government debt levels? Fiscal austerians are quick to invoke age-old textbook orthodoxies: (1) that additional borrowing will be too much for future generations to handle, citing the law of Ricardian equivalence; (2) that increased borrowing will crowd out private sector borrowing and will most likely delay the economic recovery; and (3) that bond investors will stop buying and send yields higher.

However, in the topsy-turvy world of liquidity traps, these textbook orthodoxies do not apply, and acting irresponsibly relative to orthodoxy by increasing borrowing will do more good than harm. Austerians argue that reducing deficits and putting nations’ fiscal houses in order will help growth through confidence. However, Ricardian equivalence does not work in reverse! It is not confidence, but Godley’s tyranny of arithmetic that matters: someone simply has to borrow and invest to fill missing demand.

Crowding out, overheating and rising interest rates are also not likely to be a problem as there is no competition for funds from the private sector. For evidence, look no further than the impact of government borrowing on long-term interest rates in the U.S. during the Great Depression, or more recently, Japan …

Held back by concerns borne of these orthodoxies, however, governments are not spending with passionate purpose. They are victims of intellectual paralysis borne of inertia of dogma that, in the present circumstances, do not apply. As a result, their acting responsibly relative to orthodoxy and going forth with austerity may drag economies down the vortex of deflation and depression.

The importance of fiscal expansion and the impotence of conventional monetary policy measures in a liquidity trap have profound implications for the conduct of central banks. This is because in a liquidity trap, the fat tail risk of inflation is replaced by the fat tail risk of deflation. In turn, the fatness of the deflation tail is a function of the government’s willingness and ability to pump-prime, i.e. to borrow and spend.

  1. April 17, 2014 at 8:38 pm

    Neoclassical economics may have nothing to offer. But Keynesian economics has offered
    poison. In 2002, Krugman advised:

    “…as Paul McCulley of Pimco put it, Alan Greenspan needs to create a housing bubble
    to replace the Nasdaq bubble.” See

    Needless to say we are living in the aftermath of their codswallop. Why do economists have the memory of a goldfish?

    • Thor
      April 18, 2014 at 12:02 am

      Paul Krugman is not a Keynesian economist. By name perhaps, but not by reality. The real Keynes has really been made pre-Keynesian. Really sad to see. Keynesian economics as Keynes himself put forth have never been implemented to its fullest. Post-Keynesian economists recognize that Keynes’ theories have been seriously misinterpreted in the course of time, ever since he put forward his General theory (GT). It’s absurd to think that Keynes believed in loanable funds theory after his writings. Krugman believes in the loanable funds theory, which has nothing to do with reality. The axioms of ‘Paul Krugman’ economics, so to speak, are the same axioms which govern neoclassical economics. Those are the axioms Keynes overthrew in GT.

      Keynes betrayed is an excellent book in this regard, http://www.amazon.co.uk/Keynes-Betrayed-Interest-Keynesian-Economics/dp/0230277012/ref=sr_1_1?s=books&ie=UTF8&qid=1397778898&sr=1-1&keywords=keynes+betrayed

  2. April 17, 2014 at 10:23 pm

    Perhaps, not necessarily so,”The importance of fiscal expansion and the impotence of conventional monetary policy measures in a liquidity trap have profound implications for the conduct of central banks. This is because in a liquidity trap, the fat tail risk of inflation is replaced by the fat tail risk of deflation. ”
    And perhaps we can learn from the 2002 “poison”,“…as Paul McCulley of Pimco put it, Alan Greenspan needs to create a housing bubble to replace the Nasdaq bubble.”
    What if…The Central Bank of the USA were to use a proven method to break the ‘liquidity trap’ , that would neither cause inflation nor deflation ? The Fed needs only to purchase all residential and commercial real estate loans and modify those loans with longer terms and lower interest rates.
    NO NEW money needed since this would merely be a transfer of assets from the balance sheets of the banks to the balance sheet of the Fed. The asset is already ‘only temporary
    money’ that is owed to be returned to the Fed. This would automatically “de-leverage” the banks. Inflation and deflation being a non issue.
    BUT, what about the borrower ? This would also automatically “de-leverage” the borrowers
    because of the dramatic reduction of the amount of the monthly payments.
    If $80 trillion is now @6%,@30 years, it requires over $5 trillion/year as payments.
    The modified new loans would be $80trillion @2% @40 years, that would reduce the payments to under $3trillion/year.
    How’s that for a fat cat with a thin tail.
    And now the good news! (As stated on ” 60 minutes” (12/11/11)”
    President Obama said,”You can’t raise revenues by lowering taxes unless you get the money from somewhere else.” ?
    Of the $3trillion in payments each and every year there is a “revenue income of $1 trillion
    that should be turned over to the US Treas. to be used by Congress.
    ***** “Believe nothing merely because you have been told it…But whatsoever, after due examination and analysis,you find to be kind, conducive to the good, the benefit,the welfare of all beings – that doctrine believe and cling to,and take it as your guide.”- Buddha[Gautama Siddharta] (563 – 483 BC), Hindu Prince, founder of Buddhism

    Bet you do not know WHY BEN BERNANKE couldn’t “help the people’ by doing this ?
    Because he was forced to work for the best interest of the private for profit banks, not the people who were slightly helped. Also because it would have revealed that by buying the “Ms” of the “MBSs” he would have exposed that the banks sold the future income from those notes. In the $80 trillion example that means they would have had to pay back part of the $1trillion (income gain) each year to the hedge funds.
    Oh,how I await any profound reply.

  3. April 17, 2014 at 10:33 pm

    thanks lars syll.. a very clear and lucud explanation of liquidity trap. it could explain why so poor performance under austerity.

  1. No trackbacks yet.

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.