Home > Uncategorized > Cutting-edge macroeconomics …

Cutting-edge macroeconomics …

from Lars Syll

No sooner had I finished my comment on the irrelevancy of economics but I had confirmation — albeit unwittingly — in this morning’s Financial Times.  There on the editorial page was a short column by Soumaya Keynes talking about the rise of Hank.

For those of you not on the cutting edge, “Hank” stands for Heterogeneous Agent New Keynesian, as in a complicated model of the economy.

You can put lipstick on a pig, but...... | Pig, Pigs quote, Cute pigsHank is a whole new way of looking at model economies, with the really big breakthrough being that it includes — roll the drums please — more than one household.

Yes, economists are moving at a rapid pace.  Their research has shown that the economy includes more than one household.

Gasp.

If you are a sociologist or anthropologist you are forgiven at this point for laughing out loud.

Reflect, if you will, on the enormous hubris expressed by Steve Levitt when he criticized economics for becoming too inwardly focused and potentially irrelevant.  His condemnation was absolute.  He said that economics risked falling into the kind of disrepair that, in his mind at least, make sociology and anthropology laughingstocks.  Now, I don’t know sociology or anthropology all that well, but I imagine they don’t base a substantial amount of their theoretical effort on the notion that America has only one household.  Even if that household is “representative”.

Representative of what?  Some Chicago-trained logician masquerading as an economist?

Peter Radford

Yes indeed, ‘Hank’ and similar modelling approaches are nothing but convenient untruths — and still economists rely on them to derive policy implications!

Mainstream economists seem to be impressed by the ‘rigour’ brought to macroeconomics by New-Classical-New-Keynesian DSGE models and its rational expectations and representative agent micro-foundations. It is difficult to see why.

Take the rational expectations assumption. Rational expectations in the mainstream economists’ world imply that relevant distributions have to be time-independent. This amounts to assuming that an economy is like a closed system with known stochastic probability distributions for all different events. In reality, it is straining one’s beliefs to try to represent economies as outcomes of stochastic processes. An existing economy is a single realization tout court, and hardly conceivable as one realization out of an ensemble of economy-worlds since an economy can hardly be conceived as being completely replicated over time. It is — to say the least — very difficult to see any similarity between these modelling assumptions and the expectations of real persons. In the world of the rational expectations hypothesis, we are never disappointed in any other way than when we lose at the roulette wheels. But real life is not an urn or a roulette wheel. And that’s also the reason why allowing for cases where agents make ‘predictable errors’ in DSGE models doesn’t take us any closer to a relevant and realist depiction of actual economic decisions and behaviours. If we really want to have anything of interest to say on real economies, financial crises and the decisions and choices real people make we have to replace the rational expectations hypothesis with more relevant and realistic assumptions concerning economic agents and their expectations than childish roulette and urn analogies.

‘Rigorous’ and ‘precise’ DSGE models cannot be considered anything else than unsubstantiated conjectures as long as they aren’t supported by evidence from outside the theory or model. To my knowledge no in any way decisive empirical evidence has been presented.

No matter how precise and rigorous the analysis, and no matter how hard one tries to cast the argument in modern mathematical form, they do not push economic science forward one single millimetre if they do not stand the acid test of relevance to the target. No matter how clear, precise, rigorous or certain the inferences delivered inside these models are, they do not say anything about real-world economies.

Proving things ‘rigorously’ in DSGE models is at most a starting point for doing an interesting and relevant economic analysis. Forgetting to supply export warrants to the real world makes the analysis an empty exercise in formalism without real scientific value.

The kind of knowledge and information we seek in science is something different from what we look for in fiction. Building ‘fictional’ models that we all know are false — not only in the sense that they idealize or abstract from some things (all models do) — in the sense that no matter how many corrections, amendments or ‘successive approximations’ are made, they will never be true of the real-world phenomenon they try to describe or analyze, can’t be the right way to proceed in science. Although that kind of model assumption (often of a mathematical kind) is necessary from a tractability point of view, they are far from harmless since they usually are not possible to ‘relax.’ What drives them is their exact necessary form without which the sought-after results would never obtain. If this kind of economic model — as argued by some economic methodologists — gives us the same kind of knowledge as we get in ordinary fiction, well, then surely we should seriously reconsider what we are doing. Letting tractability, rather than reason, decide what assumptions we make in our theories and models, is not what we need if we want to build a realist and relevant economic science.

Mainstream economists think there is a gain from the DSGE style of modelling in its capacity to offer some kind of structure around which to organise discussions. To me, that sounds more like religious theoretical-methodological dogma, where one paradigm rules in divine hegemony. That’s not progress. That’s the death of economics as a science.

Showing that something is possible in a ‘possible world’ doesn’t give us a justified license to infer that it therefore also is possible in the real world. ‘The Great Gatsby’ is a wonderful novel, but if you truly want to learn about what is going on in the world of finance, I would recommend rather reading Minsky or Keynes and directly confronting real-world finance.

The assumptions and descriptions we use in our modelling have to be true — or at least ‘harmlessly’ false — and give a sufficiently detailed characterization of the mechanisms and forces at work. Models in mainstream economics do nothing of the kind.

Our aspirations have to be more far-reaching than just constructing coherent and ‘credible’ models about ‘possible worlds’. We want to understand and explain ‘difference-making’ in the real world and not just in some made-up fantasy world.  Science has to be something more than just more or less realistic ‘story-telling’ or ‘explanatory fictionalism’. You have to provide decisive empirical evidence that what you can infer in your model also helps us to uncover what actually goes on in the real world.  If you fail to support your models in that way,  you come up with nothing that holds as an explanation of what goes on in the world in which we live.

Postulating ‘representative agents’ equipped with ‘rational expectations’ may help mainstream economists derive sought-after results like ‘equilibrium’, ‘stability’ and downward-sloping demand curves. But telling us that something is possible in a patently artificial fictional world inhabited by ‘representative agents’ equipped with ‘rational expectations’ is not enough. Showing us that something possibly can happen in a model world, is not enough to explain what actually happens in the real world.

  1. ghholtham
    April 19, 2024 at 4:25 pm

    I agree entirely with the points that Lars makes about DSGE and its Hank variants and I deplore the dominance of this kind of thing in university teaching and publication. But the point is no-one uses this stuff in practice. Consider all the discussion of economic policy in the press and in politics. It all assumes that fiscal policy has an effect and that the monetary system is prone to cycles or phases that central banks are supposed to stabilise. Yes, central banks have models that may use a DSGE core but then their policy-makers are fed data on consumer confidence, investment expectations, purchasing manager surveys, and all sorts of leading indicators that cannot be accommodated in such a model. What do they pay attention to when setting policy, the model or the data it cannot accommodate? The data every time. No-one practising economics in policy circles, the market, or industry believes in “rational expectations”.

    It is a shame the academics are playing with imaginary worlds but worse is that the practitioners are left to their own devices using eclectic bits and pieces of old-fashioned theory to try and stitch their understanding of the data together. There is no coherent, consensus theory of macroeconomics in actual use. Each practitioner has her own favourite indicator or favourite theoretical gizmo. Eclecticism rules and contemporary economic theory is regarded as irrelevant.

    In those circumstances it is more important to think about how a more systematic and coherent approach could be developed to help the practitioners. Criticising the academics is easy and they deserve it. But what to do about the unsatisfactory situation of the practitioners is much more important. 

  2. yoshinorishiozawa
    April 24, 2024 at 5:06 am

    G. H. Holtham and readers,

    I came to know the existence of Hank model in this Blog. I skipped two papers on Hank. Those economists who work in Hank boast that this and that that were impossible in Rank became possible. They may be right with this regards.

    I have a question. Rank and Hank both assume the validity or utility of central bank interest rate policy. In the case of Japanese economy, it was not very effective for about 30 years. The very validity of interest rate policy is questioned. Then, I want to know if there are good empirical works that estimated the dimension of peoples’ reaction (in the economy as a whole) to the change of interest rate, especially when the interest rate is very low (or nearly zero).

    If Garry or any other persons know something, please inform me.

  3. John Otto de Villiers
    April 25, 2024 at 8:33 pm

    Hank Sank (sic) used to refer to a hairstyle.

    All of the current “state of the art” circumlocutions more a sympton of a necrotic system, a more subtle manifestation than Javier Milei.

  4. yoshinorishiozawa
    April 28, 2024 at 12:28 pm

    Contemporary DSGE models represent the culmination of a failed research program. But what do we put in their place? Post-Keynesian macroeconomics has many strengths but also faces significant challenges.

    From the secon paragraph of Peter Skott 2019 Challenges for Post-Keynesian macroeconomics: a behavioural and structuralist perspective. In Jespersen and Olsen (eds.) Progressive Post-Keynesian Economics, Ch.2, pp.16-33.

    Post-Keynesians agree that aggregate demand plays a key role in both the short run and the long run. It is essential, however, to consider the dynamic interactions across goods, labor and financial markets, and the labor market and the supply side have not been getting the attention that they deserve in Post-Keynesian growth theory. The failings of the Lucas-type ‘microeconomic foundations’, second, must not lead to a neglect of microeconomic behavior. Convincing macroeconomic theories must consider and address the connections between macroeconomic relations and the microeconomic behavior whose aggregate manifestation the relations represent. Most economic behavior is goal oriented, and the goal orientation can have important implications, even though optimization in any strict sense is impossible. Microeconomic behavior, third, takes place within an institutional structure that shapes economic behavior and economic outcomes. Macroeconomic theory must be both behavioral and structuralist.

    From the second paragraph of Peter Skott 2019 Challenges for Post-Keynesian macroeconomics: a behavioural and structuralist perspective. In Jespersen and Olsen (eds.) Progressive Post-Keynesian Economics, Ch.2, pp.16-33.

    Peter Skott is much more positive than Lars Syll. He can show the future topics that heterodox economists must challenge.

  5. ghholtham
    April 29, 2024 at 4:53 pm

    Yoshi, I am unaware of any empirical work that demonstrates a stable relationship between interest rates and economic activity. One difficulty in reality is that there is a system of interest rates which do not necessarily move in unison and some rates are much more important than others for different sections of the economy. Term structure and credit spreads sit between official rates and the rates that people actually pay. In recession, for example, government bond yields may fall while credit spreads widen and private finance becomes more, not less, difficult. 

  6. ghholtham
    April 29, 2024 at 5:04 pm

    For my taste there is too much concern on this blog about what is in text books compared with what central banks, governments and other economic players actually believe and do.  Economics typically teaches students untruths. Graduate teaching and research then used to consist of explaining that what had been taught was wrong and reality was more complicated. That remains true in some institutions but many other graduate schools instead use fancy mathematics to elaborate the untruths. That activity, though, has a diminishing, and now tiny, influence on what practitioners think.

  7. yoshinorishiozawa
    May 1, 2024 at 1:38 pm

    Sorry! I made a mistake. The first citation was from the first paragraph and no from the second paragraph.

  8. yoshinorishiozawa
    May 2, 2024 at 9:12 pm

    Thank you, ghholtham. I agree with you.

    As for “what central banks, governments and other economic players actually believe and do”, I think economics (or more precisely, mainstream macro) is too much concerned with what the central banks are doing and what they should do. We should not give too much expectation on their roles. As the ten years of the Bank of Japan (under President Kuroda and Abenomics) teaches us, what they could do was the smallest thing that is imaginable. I am not thinking what they did was wrong. They did almost all they can and in the most able way. Even though, the result was quite small.

    Probably, we should change our attention from central banks to other economic affairs, such as what we teach to younger generations. What is taught in economics must be changed accordingly. It may be a possibility to change economics to a more realistic and useful one.

  1. No trackbacks yet.

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.