Home > Uncategorized > Are we at full employment? taking issue with Paul Krugman

Are we at full employment? taking issue with Paul Krugman

from Dean Baker

Paul Krugman had an interesting blog post this morning in which he attributed the continuing weakness of wage growth to an increase in monopsony power. I’m a skeptic on this one, since the collapse in wage growth happens to coincide with the Great Recession. The big issue is whether the labor market is again back to its pre-recession level of tightness, when wages were rising considerably more rapidly.

To argue the case that it is, Krugman follows Jason Furman in dismissing the drop in prime age labor force participation as just being part of a longer term trend. This leaves me uncomfortable for a couple of reasons.

First, it would be nice to have an explanation for the trend, instead of just pointing to it and saying “trend.” We have clear explanations for trends like rising incomes through time or increases in life expectancy. What is the explanation for fewer men interested in working through time? Will this decline persist forever?

That brings me to the second reason I am uncomfortable with this story. Insofar as there had been an explanation, it was usually that the skills of less educated men were less valued in the modern economy. We no longer need strong people to move things around, machines do that for us.

There undoubtedly is some truth to this story, except the drop in employment rates (EPOPs) since 2007, and especially since 2000, has been pretty much across the board. EPOPs have fallen for both men and women and at pretty much all education levels. These drops are departures from past trends. (Women’s EPOPs had been rising until the 2001 recession.) A shortage of demand is the most simple explanation for why there would be a sudden drop in EPOPs hitting pretty much every demographic group. 

The other piece of evidence Krugman and Furman cite is the rise in quit rates, which are back to their pre-recession levels. I am less impressed. The problem is there is a composition effect. Fewer people are now employed like sectors with few quits, like manufacturing, and relatively more people are employed in sectors with frequent quits like retail trade and restaurants. This means that even if quit rates are lower within a sector, they can be higher for the economy as a whole.

Here’s the picture in retail.

Quit Rate in Retail Sector

retail quit

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

And the picture in restaurants.

Quit Rate in Leisure and Hospitality Sector

restaurant quit rate

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

In both cases the quit rate is below the peaks hit in 2006 and 2007 and well below the peaks before the 2001 recession. In fact, the 4.3 percent quit rate in the restaurant sector is closer to the lows hit following the 2001 recession than the peaks in 2006 and 2007. For this reason, I don’t think the quit rate story supports the tight labor market argument. (It’s also worth noting that the share of unemployment due to voluntary quits is also below the 2006-07 levels and well below the peaks hit in 2000.)

So I still go for the slack labor market explanation for weak wage growth. This doesn’t mean monopsonistic labor markets may not be part of the story, but the big money is likely to be in pushing the labor market further.

  1. Prof Dr James Beckman, Germany
    May 22, 2018 at 4:04 pm

    From the viewpoint of business economics, it seems to me that lots of service jobs with poor compensation (including fringes) & little job security mean little incentive to stay if one is angry at the situation or “just” wants a better deal. The presence of many part-time, often grey area, jobs means there are also “non-traditional” alternatives to poor quality full-time.
    As for manufacturing positions, I suspect the better paying ones are relatively few in number, with some requiring additional skills not easily acquired (under-water welding, CAD/CAM).

  2. paul davidson
    May 22, 2018 at 4:12 pm

    suprisingly no one mentions the growing competition from overseas workers in LDCs where sweatshop conditions and pay less than the minimum wage allws foreign production to enter te ‘u”S”A at much lower total costs [ especially labor costs].

    It is free trade under globalization of production and outsourcing that can readily explain the trend in wage changes in the USA.

    • Edward K Ross
      May 23, 2018 at 12:27 am

      Great to see someone clearly identifying cheap foreign production entering the A.S.A. undercuts local production . Furthermore the cheap foreign production is at the expense of people working in sweat shops. that are generally managed by local entrepreneures exploiting their own people with the collusion of the greedy importer to countries such as the U.S.A., without any equalizing factor such as import tariffs. On this basis I find that there appears to be a growing number of people genuinely finding it increasingly difficult to find employment sufficient to meet their basic needs.

      • Prof Dr James Beckman, Germany
        May 23, 2018 at 8:31 am

        Hi, Edward, “cheap foreign products” were exactly what the U.S. offered Europe as the American hinterlands opened up with cheap grain & animal carcasses after the Civil War.
        Wonder how the European businesses being undercut in price expressed it?

  1. No trackbacks yet.

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.