Home > Uncategorized > Why and how economics must change

Why and how economics must change

from Jayati Ghosh

Economics needs greater humility, a better sense of history, and more diversity

The need for drastic change in the economics discipline has never been so urgent. Humanity faces existential crises, with planetary health and environmental challenges becoming major concerns. The global economy was already limping and fragile before the pandemic; the subsequent recovery has exposed deep and worsening inequalities not just in incomes and assets but in access to basic human needs. The resulting sociopolitical tensions and geopolitical conflicts are creating societies that may soon be dysfunctional to the point of being unlivable. All this requires transformative economic strategies. Yet the discipline’s mainstream persists in doing business as usual, as if tinkering at the margins with minor changes could have any meaningful impact.

There is a long-standing problem. Much of what is presented as received economic wisdom about how economies work and the implications of policies is at best misleading and at worst simply wrong. For decades now, a significant and powerful lobby within the discipline has peddled half-truths and even falsehoods on many critical issues for example, how financial markets work and whether they can be “efficient” without regulation; the macroeconomic and distributive implications of fiscal policies; the impact of labor market and wage deregulation on employment and unemployment; how patterns of international trade and investment affect livelihoods and the possibility of economic diversification; how private investment responds to policy incentives such as tax breaks and subsidies and to fiscal deficits; how multinational investment and global value chains affect producers and consumers; the ecological damage wrought by patterns of production and consumption; whether tighter intellectual property rights are really necessary to promote invention and innovation; and so on.

Why does this happen? The original sin could be the exclusion of the concept of power from the discourse, which effectively reinforces existing power structures and imbalances. Underlying conditions are swept aside or covered up, such as the greater power of capital compared with workers; unsustainable exploitation of nature; differential treatment of workers through social labor market segmentation; the private abuse of market power and rent-seeking behavior; the use of political power to push private economic interests within and between nations; and the distributive impacts of fiscal and monetary policies. The deep and continuing concerns with GDP as a measure of progress are ignored; despite its many conceptual and methodological flaws, it remains the basic indicator, just because it’s there.

Inconvenient truths

There is a related tendency to downplay the crucial significance of assumptions in deriving analytical results and in presenting those results in policy discussions. Most mainstream theoretical economists will argue that they have moved far away from early neoclassical assumptions such as perfect competition, constant returns to scale, and full employment, which bear no relation to actual economic functioning anywhere. But these assumptions still persist in the models that explicitly or implicitly undergird many policy prescriptions (including on trade and industrial policies or “poverty reduction” strategies), particularly for the developing world.

The power structures within the profession reinforce the mainstream in different ways, including through the tyranny of so-called top journals and academic and professional employment. Such pressures and incentives divert many of the brightest minds from a genuine study of the economy (to try to understand its workings and the implications for people) to what can only be called “trivial pursuits.” Too many top academic journals publish esoteric contributions that add value only by relaxing one small assumption in a model or using a slightly different econometric test. Elements that are harder to model or generate inconvenient truths are simply excluded, even if they would contribute to a better understanding of economic reality. Fundamental constraints or outcomes are presented as “externalities” rather than as conditions to be addressed. Economists who talk mainly to each other, then simply proselytize their findings to policymakers, are rarely forced to question this approach.

As a result, economic forces that are necessarily complex—muddied with the impact of many different variables—and reflect the effects of history, society, and politics are not studied in light of this complexity. Instead, they are squeezed into mathematically tractable models, even if this removes any resemblance to economic reality. To be fair, some very successful mainstream economists have railed against this tendency—but with little effect thus far on the gatekeepers of the profession.

Hierarchy and discrimination

The enforcement of strict power hierarchies within the discipline has suppressed the emergence and spread of alternative theories, explanations, and analysis. These combine with the other forms of discrimination (by gender, race/ethnicity, location) to exclude or marginalize alternative perspectives. The impact of location is huge: the mainstream discipline is completely dominated by the North Atlantic—specifically the US and Europe— in terms of prestige, influence, and the ability to determine the content and direction of the discipline. The enormous knowledge, insights, and contributions to economic analysis that are made by economists located in global majority countries are largely ignored, because of the implicit assumption that “real” knowledge originates in the North and is disseminated outward.

“The enforcement of strict power hierarchies within the discipline has suppressed the emergence and spread of alternative theories, explanations, and analysis.”

Arrogance toward other disciplines is a major drawback, expressed for example by the lack of a strong sense of history, which should permeate all current social and economic analysis. Recently it has become fashionable for economists to dabble in psychology, with the rise of behavioral economics and “nudges” to induce certain behavior. But this too is often presented ahistorically, without recognizing varying social and political contexts. For example, the worm’s eye randomized tests that have become so popular in development economics are associated with a shift away from studying evolutionary processes and macroeconomic tendencies, to focus on microeconomic proclivities that effectively erase the background and context that shape economic behavior and responses. The underlying and deeply problematic underpinning of methodological individualism persists, largely because few contemporary economists attempt a philosophical assessment of their own approach and work.

These flaws have greatly impoverished economics and unsurprisingly reduced its credibility and legitimacy among the wider public. The mainstream discipline is sorely in need of greater humility, a better sense of history and recognition of unequal power, and active encouragement of diversity. Clearly, much has to change if economics is really to become relevant and useful enough to confront the major challenges of our times.

  1. energyasnumeraire
    March 8, 2024 at 9:39 am

    I very much like this post.

    It pointed out, that some parts of economics today are more a set of beliefs.

    I would add a point which I find even more basic:
    The biggest flaw in my point of view is the fact that economic theory is based on the relative unit of “money value” without a defined basic “one part” of this unit of measurement.

    In fact:
    Any part of the GDP today is summed up in monetary value, with no possibility whatsoever of physical characteristic to be measured. (that seems to be unsolvable for now, but nevertheless it is true for this argument.)

    On the other hand, the connection between the total value of all products, all services of the physical side of that economic system is … only the dedicated and very selectively sorted parts in the inflation rate basket of goods.

    That is the very thin wire between the “monetary relative unit universe” and the real world parts of the GDP of a given economic system.

    But is the basket of goods really sufficient to measure any part of the total GDP of today summed up in monetary terms?

    I would hardly say: No.

    The fact, that credit is creating our money pool is clear. As long as you use a credit for buying a new house that will be build … there is some real world new product behind. That is ok.

    But there are many credits out there just financing new products in the kind of financial products …
    in other words: You create new money (by credits) to create or make more money?

    That is ridiculous. That is a complete nonsense caused by the economic theory with no real physical world based definition of economic systems.

    I mean: Try to find any economic teach book with the frist chapter of
    “what is an economic system, how is it characterised in real world and what separates its parts from nature, and how to measure it”

    I hardly fear you will not find any economic theory for now describing or answering these questions.

    That is what I want to change.

  2. Steven Klees
    March 8, 2024 at 4:21 pm

    Jayati (if I may), thank you for your insightful analysis of what is fundamentally wrong with neoclassical economics.  I have long been a fan of your work and passionate advocacy.  Perhaps the exclusion of power is the original sin, as you say, and without examining power, hierarchy, discrimination in this this world economic analyses are irrelevant, “trivial pursuits” as you say – at best.  Squeezing economics into mathematically tractable models has gotten us nowhere (see my http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue74/Klees74.pdf).  Jayati, I would love your comments on my blog version of what is fundamentally wrong with economics and where the alternatives lie (see my https://evonomics.com/klees-neoclassical-economics-failed-what-comes-next/).

  3. Kevin Cox
    March 9, 2024 at 8:01 am

    Here is an initiative for communities to take back power from the financial industry. https://forms.gle/NoKXBirm4xH3ZfBi9 starting with the transfer of house ownership. In Australia in 1980 70% of home loans were made by Credit Unions and Mutual Societies. Today 90% are made by the Australian big four banks and most Credit Unions have had to turn into Banks to compete. You can read why this happened here and our initiative will give community banks back the advantage by removing the need for bank loans and debt to transfer housing.

  4. ghholtham
    March 25, 2024 at 12:12 pm

    JG’s comments seem to me to be substantially correct.

    I don’t believe the answers lie in finding a chimerical “physical” unit for measuring economies. The best measurement will continue to depend on the question being asked. 

    While excessively simple mathematical models with analytic solutions are over-used in economics, the answer does not lie in a retreat into non-quantitative wordsmithery. We have to accept complexity and build models that reflect it and do not have simple solutions. Then we have to use computers to explore the properties of both model and, we hope, reality. It is what meteorologists and vulcanologists do when dealing with complex systems and what other social scientists do when they have the necessary data.

  5. yoshinorishiozawa
    March 26, 2024 at 1:57 pm

    ghholtham > [T]he answer does not lie in a retreat into non-quantitative wordsmithery. We have to accept complexity and build models that reflect it and do not have simple solutions.

    I support this thinking. The economy is a large complex system. We should not expect there is a simple magic that solves everything.

  1. No trackbacks yet.

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.